A value-based or a fair price?
Is “value-based pricing” a fair pricing approach?
The quick answer is “mostly No!”
WHY?
Before we answer this, we need to define "fairness.” for whom??
Now lets' look at both sides
In this article, I will try to shed some light on the main ideas discussed in his paper that tries to answer the following questions:
If this sounds interesting to you, I hope you enjoy this reading.
The Win-Win Situation and The “Total Welfare” In Economics?
The main idea in this framework is based on a fundamental concept in economics: the "total welfare" that should result from producing and purchasing any good.
?Total welfare is the total extra benefit or happiness enjoyed by producers and consumers who feel they got a good price for the product being exchanged
Let’ Talk a Bit About The Consumer.
We need to first agree that when we refer to the consumer, we mean the public payer, who is responsible for providing medicine to the entire population of a society. In other words, the consumer is?"the total population" or "the society".
For the consumer, the situation is quite simple. If you are familiar with the concept of a "cost-effectiveness threshold," you may be aware that there are two definitions?for the thresholds with?two approaches for estimating it. In this article we are mainly concerned with one of these definitions, that represents the opportunity cost.
?
In simple words, the threshold tells us, currently how much (on average) do we pay to gain one unit of health (one QALY)?
For example, if we pay $ 50,000 per one QALY, then it is irrational to purchase a drug the gives us a QALY with a cost of $100,000.
WHY?
Because if we did so it means for every new QALY we get by the new treatment we are losing 2 QALYs elsewhere in the health care system. Therefore, we are reducing the overall population health.
?From now on this cost-effectiveness threshold that is based on the health opportunity cost will be referred to as (K).
Based On This, What Can Be a Good Price For The Consumer?
As previously stated,?in economics, selling and purchasing goods should result in consumer and producer surplus. For the consumer, it represents the additional benefit of paying less than what they were willing to pay.
According to the definition of "k," the price of any drug should be less than "K" so that the health gain by?the new drug outweigh the health losses suffered by other patients in the healthcare system.
As a result, the overall population health is increasing, and we are achieving a positive "consumer surplus."
Note: in value-based pricing drugs are priced to “K” which means health gains equals health loss and the consumer surplus is ZERO. (Although this may change later after patent expiry).
What About The Producer?
When looking from the producer's perspective, one major difference is that the acceptable price is not linked to the price of a unit health (QALY), but rather to the price of the product.
The minimum acceptable price for producers should cover two costs:
Therefore, any price that exceeds these costs generates additional benefit or profit for the producer. In other words, will result in "producer surplus".
Using a Unified Unit for Both Parties
As previously stated, an acceptable price for the consumer is defined as the price per QALY, whereas for the producer it is the price per pack.
领英推荐
?To standardise price expression, we must first determine the price per QALY (ICER) that corresponds to the producer's minimum acceptable price per pack:
?The author called this value:
" The Reserve ICER"
Now, what do you think can be a good price for both the consumer and producer??
Exactly, it is the price below the threshold below (k) and above (The reserve ICER).
Why Isn't this applicable in practice?
?Though it appears simple to negotiate a fair price that benefits both parties. This is not really applicable because of three major challenges:
What Is?The Proposed Solution in Paulden’s Article?
The author proposed a common?price for all medications. In other words, all medications from all?manufacturers will have the same price per unit of health (per QALY).
This common price should of course be smaller than the cost-effectiveness threshold (K).
-For the consumer:
?-For the producer (manufacturer):
We will assume that the manufacturer has several products. These products should?match?one of three possible?scenarios:
?Overall, the supplied medications will result in both “consumer surplus” and “producer surplus”, and everyone should be satisfied .
At any ‘fair’ common price, there will generally be some medicines with low reserve ICERs for which the manufacturer receives substantial profits, and others with higher reserve ICERs for which most of the economic surplus for that medicine is allocated to patients.
The Author Also Addressed …
…. a number of other critical issues that were raised as potential topics for future research and discussion. These included (but were not limited to):
An Excellent Framework, But..
Although the proposed framework makes a lot of sense, there are a few limitations that hinder its use in practice.
?Some of them are already addressed by the author in his paper (others are?personal comments). However, the author didn't suggest practical?solutions to the one mentioned in his paper.?
?These challenges include:
Conclusion
In my opinion, these ideas remain an excellent "theoretical" foundation for the topic of "fair pricing," but it?do not provide a feasible roadmap?for implementing "fair pricing" in the real world.
?References:
Paulden, M. A Framework for the Fair Pricing of Medicines. PharmacoEconomics 42, 145–164 (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40273-023-01325-z
Disclaimers: