The Proper Price for a Domain, Part 8: Calculating a Comprehensive Price Cap | #20 in Series: What Businesses Need to Know about Domaining
Keith Borden
Articles: What Businesses Need to Know about Domaining. Not understanding the domain name industry can cost you.
In this series I address people running a business or organization of any size, from entrepreneurs to the whole C-Suite, as well as Business Development, Marketing, Sales, Finance and IT. But I welcome all readers, including of course domainers.?Series Table of Contents
In previous articles we've been developing a process to determine the worth of a domain to your company, or the maximum you should be prepared to pay for it. Here we complete that process. We get there. (At least for a single-payment purchase, that is.) Let's continue.
15) Having the money (or being able to get it) is obviously one factor in affordability. Another is what I incorrectly called 'opportunity cost' in article 15, and will here define as choice cost.
Choice cost may sound like a number of things it actually isn't. The distinctions are important.
The word choice in the term 'choice cost' does not refer to your choice to make the investment, but rather to the constraint which that choice places on your ability to choose alternative or additional purchases, costing you the loss of the option to make those purchases as well.
But the actual constraint differs from the choice cost, and depends on exactly what alternative purchases the investment precludes, as well as the extent of your financial reserves. In fact, the best way to define the actual constraint is in terms of the specific alternatives the investment precludes. So let's define another term, choice constraint, which is the actual constraint.
To understand why we need two concepts — choice cost and choice constraint — even though they're closely related, with choice constraint dependent on choice cost — it's critical to understand the difference between them.
The choice cost is a function only of the investment price, payment schedule and profit over time —financial characteristics of the investment itself — and is itself a financial quantity. By contrast, the choice constraint is not a financial quantity, and depends also on other factors.
Suppose it's the end?of the fiscal year, and you want to spend down $1 million from your budget. A $100k investment with those funds will not constrain you from also making a different $200k purchase. The choice cost of the investment is $100k, but there's no choice constraint, because there's plenty of funds to cover both purchases.
Now suppose instead that you have only $250k unallocated funds to spend down. You could still make either the $100k investment or the $200k purchase, but now the $100k investment with those funds will constrain your choice to also make the $200k purchase. The choice cost here is exactly the same as in the previous example, but the choice constraint ?is not the same as in the previous example. Notice that the value (or at least the price) of the choice constraint here is twice the choice cost.
The choice constraint tells you what you'll be giving up if you make the investment. If you really wouldn't be giving up anything, why wouldn't you make the investment, regardless of how much it cost?
领英推荐
Although the choice constraint is not directly determined by or proportional to the choice cost, the choice cost is the single financial attribute of the investment itself that most directly determines the choice constraint. And the choice cost is a function of time. Therefore, the choice cost over time is one of the most relevant attributes of the investment itself in deciding whether or not to make the investment.(2)
So with the choice cost and choice constraint concepts under your belt, once you have your maximum feasible adjusted, qualified, effective modestly cautious prospective circumspective price cap, you need to ask:
We could also call the prudent price cap a comprehensive price cap, because it takes everything together into account — for a single-payment purchase, that is.(4)
But extended payments could change the equation yet again. And that's not the only reason for making extended payments. See my next two articles.
(Like this article? 'Like' it! Have a question or comment? Comment! Think it's worth sharing? Share it! Thanks! - Keith)
___________________________
(1) Here's how that works. Suppose that if you don't make the investment, you could do A, B and C individually or in any combination. If you do make the investment, you could still do A or B or C, but not any combinations of?them. Then none of these individually would be part of the choice constraint, but each of the following sets of options would be included within the set of sets of options constituting the choice constraint: (A and B), (A and C), (B and C), and (A and B and C).
However, if you couldn't do all three (A and B and C) together even if?you don't make the investment, then the option set (A and B and C) would not be part of the investment's choice constraint, since you couldn't do it anyway — so it's not the investment that would keep you from doing it.
On the other hand, if D is another thing you'd like to do, and which you could do if you don't make the investment, and making the investment would preclude your doing it, then D would be a single-member set within the investment's choice constraint set of sets.
(2) The other two aspects of the investment itself most relevant to your price cap and decision to purchase are profit over time and the effective payback period. But these are not unrelated. Choice cost and cumulative profit are both functions of time. The effective payback period is simply the length of time from the purchase date to when choice cost permanently reaches zero as the cumulative profit overtakes the payment(s). Choice cost, in turn, is a function of the payment schedule and ongoing profit, which are the only independent variables (in the sense that they're dependent only on time).
(3) This where you determine the choice constraint, and it needs clarifying. As explained earlier, if without getting the domain you could do both A and B, and with the domain you could still do A or B, but no longer A and B, then the inability to do A or B is not an choice constraint, but the inability to do A and B is a choice constraint, providing that you would still want to do A and B if you get the domain. For more, see footnote 1.
(4) 'Comprehensive' means grasping together. The prudent price cap gives you a handle on all the factors together which should influence your domain purchase decision for a single-payment acquisition, so it's comprehensive.