Healthcare Price Transparency: More Complex Than it Sounds
Don Peppers
Customer experience expert, keynote speaker, business author, Founder of Peppers & Rogers Group
Last week during my panel discussion at the World Healthcare Congress, we had an interesting discussion about the implications of price transparency.
Today’s healthcare pricing is totally screwed up, with almost no transparency. Next time you or someone close to you has a stay in the hospital, for instance, just try to piece together what it actually cost, and what particular costs were attributable to which particular elements of care.
In his book America’s Bitter Pill, lawyer Stephen Brill points out that many of the charges healthcare providers attach to complicated procedures are not just indecipherable, but indefensible. For instance, in recounting how one chemotherapy patient’s invoice was rendered by the University of Texas’s MD Anderson Cancer Center, Brill says that one of the first itemized charges was
“1 acetaminophen tabs 325 mg.” The charge was only $ 1.50, but it was for a generic version of a Tylenol pill. You can buy 100 of them on Amazon for $ 1.49 even without a hospital’s purchasing power.
But, he said, the markups got even bolder on the second page of this patient’s bill:
$13,702 for “1 rituximab inj 660 mg.” That’s an injection of 660 milligrams of a cancer wonder drug called Rituxan. The average price paid by all hospitals for this dose is about $4,000. However, MD Anderson probably gets a volume discount that would make its cost $3,000 to $3,500.
Brill then points out that MD Anderson, officially a “non-profit” institution, made an operating profit of $531 million in fiscal 2010, giving it a very respectable 26% margin on revenues of $2.05 billion that year.
Stories like this aren’t hard to find when it comes to healthcare pricing, which is so complex and difficult to understand that consumers are for the most part just baffled.
So in view of the new “consumerized” healthcare system under the Affordable Care Act, one of the issues our panel debated was whether price transparency would fix this problem. If healthcare providers were required to disclose their complex, difficult-to-understand pricing in a more transparent way, wouldn’t consumers would be better off?
Not so fast. There are at least three reasons why price transparency may not work to restrain costs.
First, even though pricing is an important economic signal that allows any free-market economy to work more efficiently, the healthcare system isn’t a free-market system, not by a long shot. Insured consumers have very little incentive to shop for lower-cost procedures or more efficient treatments, because they bear almost no responsibility for their cost. Most co-pays are fixed amounts - $25 per office visit, for instance, or the first $2000 of a hospital procedure. So even these mechanisms don’t actually “signal” the price.
And this problem is complicated by the fact that in most consumers’ minds, price and quality are correlated. If price transparency allows a consumer to discover that one provider charges $10,000 while another charges just $2,000 for the same procedure, which one would the consumer judge to be of higher quality?
But second, price transparency will almost certainly encourage lower-priced suppliers to raise their prices. In the above example, while the $10,000 provider might trim its price a bit, it's much more likely that the $2,000 provider will raise its price. Why? Because it can, that’s why.
Something analogous happened to senior executive pay at public companies. As Dan Ariely relates in his book Predictably Irrational, during the period from 1978 to 1993, average pay for a public-company CEO climbed from just 36 times the average worker’s pay to more than 130 times. So in order to “shame” companies into holding back on lavish pay for senior executives, the Securities and Exchange Commission began requiring publicly held firms to disclose the pay of their top five executives in their financial reports. The result? CEO pay shot upward even faster in just a few years, to nearly 400 times the average worker’s pay! Ariely’s hypothesis: By making a senior executive’s pay directly comparable with other senior executives at other public companies, the SEC unintentionally generated a feeding frenzy of comparison shopping by executives. You can’t blame a CEO for competing with other CEOs to have the best package, and this became a lot easier once the SEC made the information freely available.
Imagine, for instance, what would happen if everyone's salary at your own company were suddenly known to everyone else. Do you think there would be more pressure for lower salaries in the future or higher?
But finally, the healthcare payments process is hindered by both a matrix of detailed regulations and the overly complex contractual relationships that now exist between payers, providers, and patients. The result is that even well-heeled providers such as MD Anderson sometimes have to take a loss on certain kinds of procedures or care, or they have to bear risks that they aren’t being paid adequately for. So when they do have pricing power, they want to charge more in order to make up for these money-losing processes.
The point of all this is that price transparency is not necessarily going to be a panacea for controlling healthcare costs, even if it does highlight the kind of egregious and unjustified charges that are regularly documented by investigative journalists and others.
Why must leaders keep undermining the intelligence of medical consumers?
Helping construction and home improvement manufacturers make better business decisions.
9 年David is right. Quality and price are needed for consumers to make decisions in a free market system. The Mayo clinic has an inueresting outcome based incentives for their docs so they are incentified to monimize call-backs.
Renewables Marketing Leader | Small Business Mentor | Certified Professional Coach
9 年Right, pricing transparency in isolation doesn't work. What is needed is pricing transparency in tandem with quality transparency. As Don notes, without other data on quality, we intuitively equate price to quality. Unfortunately, there is little data on healthcare quality - certainly not much that can be understood by the average guy. It's almost like conjuring at the moment with the potential for misdirection. I visited a hospital recently that had a lobby like a 5 star hotel - faux marble walls, beautiful shrubs, and yes, a guy playing a grand piano in the lobby! Looks fantastic - but who knows what the quality is like under the knife, where it really matters...?
HR & Total Rewards Leader | MBA | CHHR | CCP | CHFP | Driving Strategic Solutions & Workforce Transformation in Healthcare
9 年Co-pays are going by the way-side in favor of co-insurance and high deductible plans (at least, long-term trends in the US); so there is at least some evidence from these trends that consumers are, in fact, shopping based on quality AND price given the circumstances. I'd also argue that pricing transparency is NOT akin to the rise in CEO pay. There is no "competition" to see who can charge the highest prices and get away with it. So, while, in some cases prices will rise - in others, transparency should certainly cause competition. Price does signal quality, however - and with limited downsides (even with a high deductible, $3500 is "limited" versus a 5- or 6-figure procedure), it's certainly fair to say healthcare does not operate like a free market.
Me dedico a estudiar e investigar diversos temas de actualización.
9 年Cuidado de la salud: existe desde los "objetivos mínimos", pero deben ser para todos. Y los objetivos máximos, para continuar el desarrollo de la ciencia.