Equity and Efficiency, The Cost-Sharing Tradeoff

Equity and Efficiency, The Cost-Sharing Tradeoff

In his classic 1975 book titled?Equality and Efficiency: The Big Tradeoff,?economist Art Okun noted the tensions between the political principles of democracy and the economic principles of capitalism. Some decisions yield more equality with less efficiency, and some yield more efficiency with less equality. Brilliant.

In 2018, a team of economists at the University of Southern California’s Schaeffer Center for Health Policy & Economics?reported?that 23% of pharmacy prescriptions filled by commercially insured patients in 2013 exceeded the average reimbursement from PBMs to retail pharmacies. The USC team’s?supporting video?and related press coverage suggested impropriety on the part of payers. Myopic.

For a more comprehensive understanding of cost sharing, it is instructive to trace the history, understand the objectives behind cost sharing, review some economic theory, consider equity-and-efficiency tradeoffs, and focus on the true challenge.

The history

Copayments, coinsurance, and deductibles emerged in the 1950s when private insurers competing with the Blues introduced major medical plans. Such cost sharing enabled insurers to improve access to care by covering more services with a premium that was comparable to the prevailing first-dollar coverage offered by the Blues. In response, the Blues started offering plans with these same cost-sharing features. Cost sharing has always been a means to maintain or expand access and to manage costs. Arguments for and against cost sharing are as old as cost sharing itself.

The objectives

Payers still use copays and other types of cost sharing to help manage their pharmacy costs. By giving members some “skin in the game,” copays are meant to discourage unnecessary care and encourage adherence to necessary care. Copays and co-insurance are predictable sources of revenue that payers use to offset expenses, and this is reflected in the premiums. Does cost sharing of drugs and other services sometimes exceed the costs? Yes. But is such “overpayment” an objective? No. And, importantly, nor is ensuring that a member’s cost obligation is less than the full cost of the product.

The economic theory

Why, then, does cost sharing sometimes exceed the costs? That’s simple: It is more efficient. Take, for example, a common $10 copay for generic drugs. It is a nice round number. It is easy to communicate and understand. It is generally affordable. It is somewhat effective at reducing both overuse and underuse. But it yields many so-called “overpayments” because there are plenty of commonly-used generic drugs that cost less than $10 per month. The USC economists observed that overpayments were more likely on claims for generic versus brand drugs (28% versus 6%), and that the average overpayment was $7.69. While not explicitly stated in the report, it appears that these overpayments typically live within the common $10 copay for generic drugs.

It is unfortunate that the USC economists focused only on the downside of such transactions but failed to point out the upside — that cost sharing lowers or slows the increase of premiums. It is also unfortunate that the USC economists used the charged term “clawbacks” to describe such overpayments. And it is unfortunate that the USC economists were overly simplistic when suggesting that the insurer or PBM pockets the difference — failing to acknowledge the administrative and transaction costs they incur.

The USC team discussed only overpayments, never mentioning “underpayments” — and this reveals their unstated but clear presupposition that copayments should be less than the total cost of the drug. When some patients pay more than the total cost and some pay less, then there are cross-subsidies across patients.

Are there alternatives to such cross-subsidization? Of course. Conceivably, copayments could be patient-specific or drug-specific. But how would that be assessed? And would that be equitable and/or efficient? Another option would be to increase the current cross-subsidization from those not taking drugs to those taking drugs. Alternatively, co-insurance, often reserved for specialty tiers, could be used for nonspecialty tiers. Doing so would help ensure (but not necessarily guarantee) that the amount paid does not exceed the total cost of the drug.

The RAND experiment demonstrated that demand for health care is elastic (i.e., as cost-sharing goes up, utilization goes down). While most people with high cost sharing did not experience worse outcomes, the RAND experiment showed how cost sharing negatively impacted lower-income people. In the 40 years since the RAND findings were published, there has been ample evidence to show that cost sharing can have negative impacts on patients with lower or fixed incomes, particularly those with chronic conditions, multiple conditions, and conditions requiring expensive treatments. Payers share these concerns, and they welcome patient-assistance programs designed to help people that qualify for financial assistance.

The USC economists’ estimate of savings makes no attempt to estimate the economic incidence of overpayments. A more rigorous assessment may conclude that overpayments yield savings for nearly all commercially insured lives.

The equity-and-efficiency tradeoffs

When payers make cost-sharing decisions, equity-and-efficiency tradeoffs are inevitable. Some cost-sharing designs may be more efficient but less equitable, and some designs may be more equitable but less efficient.

At first blush, charging everyone the same amount is more efficient but less equitable — it is regressive. But when the impact on premiums is part of the calculus, a more efficient cost-sharing design may lower premiums and, as a result, be less costly, more accessible, and (somewhat unexpectedly) more equitable.

Using co-insurance to charge everyone based on the cost of the product is even more regressive and less equitable — but efficient. While co-insurance for less-expensive drugs may be palatable and often less than copayments, many would find co-insurance for more expensive drugs to be less affordable than copayments.

Charging everyone based on ability to pay is more equitable — it is progressive, but less efficient. And what initially appears to be a more equitable cost-sharing design may increase premiums and, as a result, be more costly, less accessible, and, somewhat surprisingly, less equitable.

The true challenge

Eliminating overpayments is not the challenge. The challenge is to provide targeted relief to those who cannot afford cost sharing for medically necessary care. Whether cost sharing is an overpayment or an underpayment is immaterial. Meeting this challenge efficiently and equitably often requires a tradeoff. Payers can try to lead the way and develop solutions, but employers and their consultants will continue to make most of the cost-sharing decisions (good and bad) for commercial lives.

Joshua Cohen

Independent Healthcare Analyst: Joshua P. Cohen Healthcare Analytics, LLC

2 年

Great post, Camm. My fundamental issue with patient cost-sharing is not that there are co-payments. When appropriately designed, co-payments can lead to better, more rational decisions on the part of (most) patients. However, rebates - the way they're currently constituted - prevent a rational co-payment system from being instituted. Since patient co-insurance is a function of list price, the patient gets the short end of the stick of the ratcheting down of net prices through rebates. Perversely, sometimes rebates lead to preferred formulary positioning of more expensive products, even when these should not be preferred (eg, originator biologics v. biosimilars). And, the gross-to-net bubble doesn't benefit patients as much as it does PBMs. Even if the net prices are passed through to employers, this does not invariably lead to lower premiums, or lower premium rate growth necessarily.

回复
Glen Misek

Dir Global Business Insights, Abbott Laboratories

2 年

Interesting yet misses the issues that some patients have conditions that only respond to medications on higher tiers. Hence the cost sharing really ends up being discriminatory to these individuals. This is especially true among patients with conditions that’s only respond to specific biological which may not be on preferred formularies. While bio pharma companies can assist those copays for US patients under 65 those Medicare patients are left with the cost burden due to being unlucky. There are also countless individuals for whom basic generics do not deliver the proper therapeutic dose as the manufacturer may use filler and or binders that affect dissolution and absorption. Where is the equity in that?

回复
Harris Kaplan

Life Sciences Company Commercial Strategy Consultant

2 年

Very well done. Would make a great articke

回复
Richard Embrey, MD MBA

Medical Director | Creative clinical leader | Heart surgeon | Bridging the gap between the practice of medicine and the business of health care

2 年

Great piece - very insightful and thoughtful. The efficiency/equity tradeoff extends well beyond healthcare to things such as education. I believe that the purpose of copays and deductibles is not truly cost sharing, but rather is a form of disincentive to patients to overuse and abuse health services when it is "free.". Everyone should read Chapter 3 in Dan Ariely's book Predictably Irrational, aptly entitled "The Cost of Zero Cost." Even a small cost reduces the wild overuse of services when they have no cost whatsoever. As such, the overpayments or "clawbacks" that insurance companies receive when the copay is higher than the cost of the generic is irrelevant. Those tiny amounts are trivial compared to the monies flowing in the other direction. The $3 the patient overpays for the amoxicillin prescription doesn't begin to offset the $40 difference the insurance company paid for the urgent care visit to get the script for the UTI. But the efficiency/equity tradeoff is also exactly the reason we have Medicaid and Medicare programs run by the government. Publicly administered and subsidized programs can move the setpoint towards equity to a degree that would not be possible in commercial programs. That is probably a very good thing.

回复

https://pharmaphorum.com/news/supply-chain-middlemen-pocket-half-of-us-branded-medicine-spending/ "In 2020, over half of total spending on brand medicines went to the supply chain, middlemen and other stakeholders, overtaking the amount going to drug manufacturers for the first time, according to a new study."

要查看或添加评论,请登录

Camm Epstein的更多文章

社区洞察

其他会员也浏览了