Braess’s paradox and generated traffic – comparing apples and oranges
Tom van Vuren MBE
Chartered Transport Planning Professional. Visiting Professor University of Leeds. Board Member at Transport Planning Society. Head of Digital Transport at Amey. Director at Van Vuren Analytics Ltd.
Long considered an interesting but to me ultimately a whimsical mathematical construct, Braess’s paradox has increased in popularity as a reference for the folly of investing in roads, generally linking the paradox to the general finding that new roads generate new traffic.
Personally, as an equilibrium modeller, I welcome the increased prominence of Braess’s paradox – it is a good introduction to the concept of equilibrium, the difference between user equilibrium and system optimum route choice, and what is possible if through planning, pricing we can move from selfish to cooperative behaviour. By the way, the difference between these two traffic states is sometimes called the price of anarchy (see O’Hare, Connors and Watling (2016) for a good description).
But Braess’s paradox is not responsible for, or even a reasonable explanation of induced demand, generated traffic, and therefore it is time to set the record straight.
The paradox was first described in a German paper by Dietrich Braess in 1968 and, according to the very accessible and fascinating description by Nagurney and Nagurney (2022), lay undiscovered by the English reading public till it was translated by John Murdoch in 1970.
To explain the paradox, it is worth copying the simple network that Braess used (borrowed here from Nagurney and Nagurney, 2022, and illustrated at the top of this article)
The original network (left) consists of two routes 1-2-4 using links a and c and route 1-3-4 using links b and d; in the after situation (right) a new one-way link e is introduced enabling a third route 1-2-3-4 that uses links a, e and d.
The cost functions for all five links are as follows:
It is worthwhile understanding what these functions imply:
It is important to note that link e is one way, connecting the two narrow roads with a high-capacity bridge. Also, the cost functions of links a and d are such that at free flow they cost 0 units to traverse, whereas then the costs of links b and d are already 50 units. Only at link flows exceeding 6 vehicles per hour (vph) the costs of links b and c (60 units) are greater than those of links b and d (56 units).
In the before case, any demand between origin 1 and destination 4 will generate a 50/50 split between the two feasible routes. In Braess’s example a total demand of 6 vph is assumed and this demand distributes itself in a user equilibrium evenly across the two routes, 3 vph per route, at a cost of 30+53=83 units (you can easily check this yourself).
With link e introduced, the alternative 1-2-3-4 offers a new lower cost alternative at the original flow distribution (30+30+10=70 units) compared to the existing cost of 83 units, and the equilibrium is disturbed. Remember, at equilibrium all used routes are of equal length and shorter than any unused routes. Traffic re-routes and for the example of a total demand of 6 vph a new equilibrium is established with 2 vehicles using each of routes 1-2-4, 1-3-4 and 1-2-3-4. Every traveller now experiences a cost of 92 units (again, you can check this out for yourself). This is a deterioration in the costs from the situation before the bridge was built; hence the paradox that adding more capacity leads to longer travel times. Note that the original route pattern is still feasible, but that this could not be an equilibrium as in that situation there exists an unused alternative with a lower cost – in this case the price of anarchy is 92-83=9 units.
领英推荐
How is this possible? It’s because there are three specifically fabricated conditions:
?This is why using the Braess paradox to explain induced demand is so unhelpful.
Braess’s paradox is about route choice and equilibrium modelling. Does this mean that Braess’ paradox is not of any use? Not necessarily. It illustrates nicely that in any equilibrium context selfish optimisation may lead to suboptimal outcomes in which everyone loses; and that intervention may be required to stop that from happening, supporting the case for marginal cost road pricing, for instance.
For me, generated or disappearing traffic is much more easily explained by economic arguments rather than clever maths: make something cheaper and people will buy or use it more, increase the price and they will find alternatives. Best leave Braess’s paradox in textbooks for Master’s courses in transport.
References
Braess, D., 1968. Ueber ein Paradoxon aus der Verkehrsplanung. Unternehmensforschung 12, 258-268 (https://homepage.ruhr-uni-bochum.de/dietrich.braess/paradox.pdf )
Murchland J.D., 1970. Braess’s Paradox of Traffic Flow. Transportation Research 4, 391-394.
Nagurney, A. and Nagurney, L.S., 2022. The Braess Paradox, Invited Chapter for International Encyclopedia of Transportation, R. Vickerman, Editor, Elsevier (https://supernet.isenberg.umass.edu/articles/braess-encyc.pdf )
O'Hare, S., Connors, R.D. and Watling, D.P., 2016. Mechanisms that Govern how the Price of Anarchy varies with Travel Demand. Transportation Research Part B: Methodological, 84. pp. 55-80. https://eprints.whiterose.ac.uk/92812/8/TRB-OHareConnorsWatling.pdf
Pas, E.I. and Principio, S.L., 1997. Braess’ Paradox: Some New Insights. Transportation Research B 31(3), 265-276.
Economist-Econometric Modeller within Transportation, regional and Urban Economics, founder of PAM-Predictive Analytics & Modelling.
10 个月Thanks, Tom, as always, I find your rational economic way of thinking refreshing. If I may, I also want to mention that economic theory, in this case, assumes that individuals have perfect information about the cost of various paths they can choose. However, in real life, we don't have access to such perfect information (who hasn't tried a new path and found it more costly than the one they usually take). I haven't investigated this and can't back it up with evidence, still, have a feeling that the mismatch between the system optimum and user equilibrium is probably even larger in real life due to imperfect information, leading to more sub-optimal choices, which in turn should increase the risk for Braess's paradox.
This was only one of John Murchlands delightful and insightful papers in the late 1960s and early 1970s. Sadly most remained working papers from his TSu at the London Business School. I think I still have one or two
Admissions Officer at American School of Warsaw
1 年Are there any mistake on these sentences? I think you meant, link a and d which are short, while b and c are high-capacity routes, right? I hope I understand it correctly. "Links a and c are short, direct routes but with very low capacity (no fixed costs but high marginal costs) – think narrow city centre roads Links b and d are high-capacity routes but quite a bit longer (fixed costs of 50 units, but with much lower marginal costs than links a and c) – think wide dual carriageway bypasses"
Transportation Planning
2 年There are a handful of places where it is claimed to be true. Seoul, Boston, New York, London. I would love to have the time (and data) to model before/after to see if any of these are actually due to Braess' Paradox, or are just deterring/diverting/suppressing traffic which is subject to higher costs.
Professor Transport and Mobility
2 年Unfortunately there are so few planning tools that accurately catch the generative effect of new transport infrastructure, in my courses at ULiège, I show the effect of non-inclusion of accessibility-based measures in the demand generation, but how many operational platforms catch this accurately? Seems like a good thesis subject ;)